The concept of market (Part 3)

[El nombre de esta sección es “artículos en cuotas”. La idea es, como en una novela por entregas, ir subiendo partes de papers a medida que vayan saliendo. El texto abajo es un borrador de un artículo en el que trabajo. Presenté la primera versión en EGOS este año y esto que estoy subiendo acá es una segunda versión, pero aun, borrador y sin edición del inglés. Además de la introducción, el artículo se compondrá de cuatro secciones. Cada parte será una entrega que iré subiendo a medida que tenga las nuevas versiones listas. El texto abajo es la tercera entrega. Como siempre, sugerencias son muy bienvenidas]

The concept of Market (Part 3): Conceptual stances after the concept of organization

(Part 1 available here, and Part 2 here)

draft 14/12/2017

Sociologist of Czech origin, Egon Bittner published in 1965 a paper titled ‘The Concept of Organization’. The article problematized some of the challenges notions like ‘formal and rational organization’ pose to the researchers that use them.

In Bittner’s words:

‘the sociologist finds himself [sic] in the position of having borrowed a concept from those he seeks to study in order to describe what he observes about them’ (Bittner 2013 [1965]; p.176).

Concepts like formal and rational organization are used by researchers, like sociologists and experts in management, and are used also by practitioners involved in the everyday practice of organizing, such as managers and consultants. Researchers, Bittner explains, have so far followed two strategies to deal with this situation. Often times, they ‘proceed to investigate formal organization while assuming that the unexplicated common-sense meanings of the terms are adequate definitions’ (Bittner 2013 [1965]; p.180). Notions like formal and rational organization are taken as terms that are understood by those who use them and therefore do not need a more specific treatment. Other times, researchers take an almost opposite path. They provide technical definitions for terms such as organization that might well contradict the meaning given to these notions in their ordinary usage. In this latter case, ‘interest in the actor’s perspective is either deliberately abandoned, or some fictitious version of it is adopted’ (Bittner 2013 [1965]; p.176). The two strategies, Bittner suggests, are unsatisfactory. In his view, social researchers cannot simply ignore the fact that notions like formal and rational organization are part of their object of inquiry; these are ‘schemes of interpretation that competent and entitled users can invoke in yet unknown ways whenever it suits their purposes’ (Bittner 2013 [1965]; p.182). Accordingly, researchers should develop analytical strategies to study how actors skillfully use and deploy these terms in their practices. For instance: they could study how different activities are deemed irrational and which ones are tolerated or how actors invoke different meanings of a similar concept in different situations.

Bittner’s paper was part of a wider debate conducted at the time. This was a period in which – inspired by the work of Wittgenstein and developments in pragmatism and phenomenology – some of the basic principles of social research set early in the century, including the nature of social scientific concepts (Blumer 1954, Schutz 1953) were importantly problematized. Bittner’s contribution was set against Weber’s strong demarcation between scientific and everyday idealizations. In his hugely influential methodological writings, Weber strongly warmed against the negative consequences of confusing native terms and concepts. In his words:

‘the use of the undifferentiated collective concepts of everyday speech is always a cloak for confusion of thought and action. It is, indeed, very often an instrument of specious and fraudulent procedures’ (Weber 1949; p. 64).

When scientific concepts and normative ideals are confused, Weber claimed:

‘ideas are naturally no longer purely logical auxiliary devices, no longer concepts with which reality is compared, but ideals by which it is value-judged […] The sphere of empirical science has been left behind and we are confronted with a profession of faith, not an ideal typical construct’ (Weber 1949; pp. 56-57).

In Weber’s view, social scientific concepts have to be clearly separated from everyday notions. But, it is not that Bittner expected to fuse the terms of everyday action and social research. What he attempted, instead, was to provide a different type of social scientific position. From this position, everyday conceptualizations become objects of inquiry; the analysist observes the work made by social actors in defining the situations in which they take part. A position such as Bittner’s, requires, in turn, of new social scientific concepts that can equip this particular analytical angle. This is what he actually does in his collaboration with Garfinkel, for instance in the well-known piece, ‘Good organizational reasons for ‘bad’ clinic records’ (Garfinkel & Bittner 1984 [1967]).

From our contemporary perspective, it could be said that one of the legacies of these mid-20th century discussions is an important bifurcation. At the moment of confronting notions such as organization, researchers, explicitly or implicitly, have to choose. As Howard Becker succinctly put it, sociologists can either let ‘the concept defines the case’ or let ‘the case defines the concept’ (Becker 1998; p. 124). After Bittner, researchers interested in studying organization do not only have to choose between different definitions of organization, but between different conceptual stances. Stances, as Du Gay and Vikkelsø have recently explained (2017), do not refer to different statements about an object, but, different scientific attitudes. Different conceptual stances, to borrow now from Deleuze’s and Guattari (2014), ask different requirements for the research personae that use them. Researchers can follow the classical stance set by Weber, in which the task of the social researcher is to develop neatly defined ‘thought constructs’ that ought to be clearly distinguished from the notions used in everyday speech and normative-practical action. Or, researchers can take Bittner’s ethnomethodological alternative, in which the analyst studies how concepts are deployed and defined by those who use them in their own practices.

The next section answers the question of what if the distinction between conceptual stances introduced here in relation to the concept of organization is used to organize recent research dealing with the different but equally troubled concept of the market.

José Ossandón

References

Ahrne, G., Aspers, P. and Brunsson, N. (2015). The organization of markets. Organization Studies36 (1), 7 – 27.

Antal, A. B., Hutter, M., & Stark, D. (Eds.). (2015). Moments of valuation: exploring sites of dissonance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Aspers, P. (2011). Markets. Cambridge: Polity Press.

Baker, W. E. (1984). The social structure of a national securities market. American Journal of Sociology, 89(4), 775-811.

Becker, H. (1998). Tricks of the trade: How to think about your research while you’re doing it. University of Chicago Press.

Breslau, D. (2013). Designing a market-like entity: Economics in the politics of market formation. Social Studies of Science, 43(6), 829-85.

Breslau, D. (2011). What Do Market Designers Do When They Design Markets? In C. Camic, N. Gross, & M. Lamont, Social Knowledge in the Making (pp. 380–403). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Bittner, E. (1965). The concept of organization. Social Research, 239-255 [page numbers used here refer version reprinted in Ethnographic Studies 2013].

Bittner, E., & Garfinkel, H. (1984) [1967]. “Good’organizational reasons for’bad’clinical records”, in Garfinkel, H. Studies in Ethnomethodology. Cambridge: Polity Press.

Blumer, H. (1954). What is wrong with social theory? American sociological review, 19(1), 3-10.

Borch, C. (2013). The Politics of Crowds: An Alternative History of Sociology. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Callon, M. (1998). Introduction: The embeddedness of economic markets in economics. In Callon, M. (Ed.), The laws of the markets (pp. 1–57). Oxford: Blackwell.

Callon, M. (1980). ‘Struggles and negotiations to define what is problematic and what is not’. In Knorr, K, R. Krohn, & R. Whitley (eds.), The social process of scientific investigation (pp. 197–219). Amsterdam: Springer.

Callon, M. and Muniesa, F. (2005). Economic Markets as Calculative Collective Devices. Organization Studies, 26(8), 1229-1250.

Cantillon, E. (2017). Broadening the market design approach to school choice. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 33(4), 613-634.

Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the Firm. Economica, 4(16), 386-405.

Cochoy, F., Deville, J., McFall, L. (eds.) (2017) Markets and the Arts of Attachment. London: Routledge.

Cordero, R. (2016) Crisis and Critique: On the Fragile Foundations of Social Life. London, Routledge.

Christophers, B. (2015). The Law’s Markets: Envisioning and effecting the boundaries of competition. Journal of Cultural Economy, 8(2), 125-143.

Dardot, P., & Laval, C. (2013). The New Way of the World: On Neo-liberal Society. (Gregory Elliot, Trans). Brooklyn, OH: Verso.

Deleuze, G., & Guattari, F. (2014). What is philosophy? NYC: Columbia University Press.

Depeyre, C., & Dumez, H. (2008). What is a market? A Wittgensteinian exercise. European Management Review, 5(4), 225-231.

Duflo, E., 2017. ‘The Economist as Plumber’, National Bureau of Economic Research, retrieved from: https://economics.mit.edu/files/12569

du Gay, P., & Vikkelsø, S. (2017). For Formal Organization: The Past in the Present and Future of Organization Theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Dumez, H. (2016). Comprehensive Research. A methodological and epistemological introduction to qualitative research. Frederiksberg: Copenhagen Business School Press.

Edelman, B. (2017). The market design and policy of online review platforms. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 33(4), 635-649.

Fligstein, N. (1996). Markets as Politics: a Political-Cultural Approach to Market Institutions. American Sociological Review, 61, 656-673.

Foucault, M. (2008). The Birth of Biopolitics: Lectures at the Collège de France, 1978—1979. (G. Burchell, Trans.). Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

Foucault, M. (1980). Power/knowledge: Selected Interviews and Other Writings, 1972-1977. New York: Harvester Wheatsheaf.

Frankel, C. (2011). In the Image of the Market. In Farías, I. & Ossandón, J. (eds.) Comunicaciones, Semánticas y Redes, México DF: Universidad Iberoamericana.

Frankel, C. (2015). The multiple-markets problem. Journal of Cultural Economy, 8(4), 538-546.

Frankel, C., Ossandón, J., & Pallesen, T. (2017). ‘The organization of markets for collective concerns’, submitted manuscript.

Garcia-Parpet, MF. (2011) ‘Symbolic value and the establishment of prices: globalization of the wine market’. In Beckert, J., & Aspers, P. (eds.). The worth of goods: Valuation and pricing in the economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 131-154.

Ginzburg, C. (2004). Family resemblances and family trees: two cognitive metaphors. Critical Inquiry, 30(3), 537-556.

Granovetter, M. (1973). The strength of weak ties. American Journal of Sociology,78(6), 1360-1380.

Hayek, F. (1991). Spontaneous (‘grown’) order and organized (‘made’) order. In Thompson, G., Frances, J., Levačić, R. and Mitchell, J. (eds.) Markets,Hierarchies & Networks – The Coordination of Social Life. London: Sage Publications.

Jenle, R. P. (2015). Engineering Markets for Control: Integrating Wind Power into the Danish Electricity System, PhD Thesis, Copenhagen Business School.

Karpik, L. (2010) Valuing the Unique: The Economics of Singularities. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Kornberger, M., Justesen, L., Mouritsen, J. Madsen, AK. (eds.) (2015) Making Things Valuable. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Koselleck, R. (1982). Begriffsgeschichte and Social History. Economy and Society, 11(4), 409-427.

Krippner, G. R. (2002). The elusive market: Embeddedness and the paradigm of economic sociology. Theory and Society, 30(6), 775–810. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1013330324198

Langley, P. & Leyshon, A. (2016) ‘Platform capitalism: the intermediation and capitalisation of digital economic circulation.’ Finance & society, online first, 1-21.

MacKenzie, D. A., & Millo, Y. (2003). Constructing a Market, Performing Theory: The Historical Sociology of a Financial Derivatives Exchange. American Journal of Sociology109(4), 107–145.

March, J. G. (1962). The Business Firm as a Political Coalition. The Journal of Politics, 24(4), 662–678.

McFall, L. and Ossandón, J. (2014). What’s New in the ‘New, New Economic Sociology’ and should Organisation Studies care? In Adler, P., du Gay, P., Morgan, G. and Reed, M. (Eds.), Oxford Handbook of Sociology, Social Theory and Organization Studies: Contemporary Currents. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

McMillan, J. (2002). Reinventing the Bazaar: A Natural History of Markets. New York: W. W. Norton & Company.

Mirowski, P. (2013). Never Let a Serious Crisis Go to Waste. How Neoliberalism Survived the Financial Meltdown. London: Verso.

Neyland, D., Ehrenstein, V., Milyaeva, V. (2017) ‘On the Difficulties of Solving Problems through Markets: Interventions, Accountability Devices and Recursion’, submitted manuscript.

Nik-Khah, E. & Mirowski, P. (2017) ‘On going the market one better’, submitted manuscript.

Onto, G. (2016). The market as lived experience. Vibrant, 11(1): 159-190.

Ossandón, J. (2015). ‘Insurance and the Sociologies of Markets’, Economic SociologyEuropean Newsletter 17 (1), 6-15.

Ossandón, J. & Ureta, S. (2017) ‘Problematizing markets and the inner movement of neoliberalism’, submitted manuscript.

Pallesen, T. & Jenle, R. (2017) ‘Synthetic markets and the design of economic institutions’, submitted manuscript.

Rabinow, P. (2011). The Accompaniment: Assembling the Contemporary. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Roth, A. E. (2007). The Art of Designing Markets. Harvard Business ReviewOctober, 1–8.

Roth, A. E. (2002). ‘The Economist as Engineer: Game Theory, Experimentation, and Computation as Tools for Design Economics’, Econometrica, 70(4), 1341–1378.

Schutz, A., 1953. Common-Sense and Scientific Interpretation of Human Action. Philosophy and Phenomenological Research, 14(1), pp.1-38.

Somers, M. R. (1995). What’s Political or Cultural about Political Culture and the Public Sphere? Toward an Historical Sociology of Concept Formation. Sociological Theory13(2), 113–144. https://doi.org/10.2307/202157

Swedberg, R. (1994). Markets as social structures. In NJ Smelser & R. Swedberg (eds.), The Handbook of Economic Sociology, pp. 255-282. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Tribe, K. (2015). The Economy of the Word: Language, History, and Economics.

Uzzi, B. (1999). Embeddedness in the making of financial capital: How social relations and networks benefit firms seeking financing. American Sociological Review, 61(4), 481-505.

Weber, M. (1949). Objectivity in social science and social policy. In Shils, E. A., & Finch, H. A. (eds) The methodology of the social sciences. Max Weber, NYC.

White, H. (1981). Where Do Markets Come From?. American Journal of Sociology, 87(3), 517–547.

Williamson, O. (1973). Markets and Hierarchies: Some Elementary Considerations. The American Economic Review, 63 (2), 316-325.

Wilson, R. (1999). Market architecture, Presidential speech at the annual meeting of Econometrica Society, retrieved from: http://econ2.econ.iastate.edu/tesfatsi/MarketArchitecture.RWilson1999.pdf

Post a comment or leave a trackback: Trackback URL.

Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out /  Change )

Twitter picture

You are commenting using your Twitter account. Log Out /  Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out /  Change )

Connecting to %s

%d bloggers like this: